Warning: Undefined array key "rcommentid" in /customers/6/5/f/pcm.me/httpd.www/wp-content/plugins/wp-recaptcha/recaptcha.php on line 348 Warning: Undefined array key "rchash" in /customers/6/5/f/pcm.me/httpd.www/wp-content/plugins/wp-recaptcha/recaptcha.php on line 349
The model of pure competition implies that risk-adjusted rates of return should be constant across firms and industries. However, numerous economic studies have affirmed that different industries can sustain different levels of profitability; part of this difference is explained by industry structure.
Michael Porter provided a framework that models an industry as being influenced by five forces. The strategic business manager seeking to develop an edge over rival firms can use this model to better understand the industry context in which the firm operates.
Diagram of Porter’s 5 Forces
|
SUPPLIER POWER |
|
BARRIERS |
|
THREAT OF |
|
BUYER POWER |
DEGREE OF RIVALRY |
I. Rivalry
In the traditional economic model, competition among rival firms drives profits to zero. But competition is not perfect and firms are not unsophisticated passive price takers. Rather, firms strive for a competitive advantage over their rivals. The intensity of rivalry among firms varies across industries, and strategic analysts are interested in these differences.
Economists measure rivalry by indicators of industry concentration. The Concentration Ratio (CR) is one such measure. The Bureau of Census periodically reports the CR for major Standard Industrial Classifications (SIC’s). The CR indicates the percent of market share held by the four largest firms (CR’s for the largest 8, 25, and 50 firms in an industry also are available). A high concentration ratio indicates that a high concentration of market share is held by the largest firms – the industry is concentrated. With only a few firms holding a large market share, the competitive landscape is less competitive (closer to a monopoly). A low concentration ratio indicates that the industry is characterized by many rivals, none of which has a significant market share. These fragmented markets are said to be competitive. The concentration ratio is not the only available measure; the trend is to define industries in terms that convey more information than distribution of market share.
If rivalry among firms in an industry is low, the industry is considered to be disciplined. This discipline may result from the industry’s history of competition, the role of a leading firm, or informal compliance with a generally understood code of conduct. Explicit collusion generally is illegal and not an option; in low-rivalry industries competitive moves must be constrained informally. However, a maverick firm seeking a competitive advantage can displace the otherwise disciplined market.
When a rival acts in a way that elicits a counter-response by other firms, rivalry intensifies. The intensity of rivalry commonly is referred to as being cutthroat, intense, moderate, or weak, based on the firms’ aggressiveness in attempting to gain an advantage.
In pursuing an advantage over its rivals, a firm can choose from several competitive moves:
The intensity of rivalry is influenced by the following industry characteristics:
BCG founder Bruce Henderson generalized this observation as the Rule of Three and Four: a stable market will not have more than three significant competitors, and the largest competitor will have no more than four times the market share of the smallest. If this rule is true, it implies that:
Whatever the merits of this rule for stable markets, it is clear that market stability and changes in supply and demand affect rivalry. Cyclical demand tends to create cutthroat competition. This is true in the disposable diaper industry in which demand fluctuates with birth rates, and in the greeting card industry in which there are more predictable business cycles.
II. Threat Of SubstitutesIn Porter’s model, substitute products refer to products in other industries. To the economist, a threat of substitutes exists when a product’s demand is affected by the price change of a substitute product. A product’s price elasticity is affected by substitute products – as more substitutes become available, the demand becomes more elastic since customers have more alternatives. A close substitute product constrains the ability of firms in an industry to raise prices.
The competition engendered by a Threat of Substitute comes from products outside the industry. The price of aluminum beverage cans is constrained by the price of glass bottles, steel cans, and plastic containers. These containers are substitutes, yet they are not rivals in the aluminum can industry. To the manufacturer of automobile tires, tire retreads are a substitute. Today, new tires are not so expensive that car owners give much consideration to retreading old tires. But in the trucking industry new tires are expensive and tires must be replaced often. In the truck tire market, retreading remains a viable substitute industry. In the disposable diaper industry, cloth diapers are a substitute and their prices constrain the price of disposables.
While the threat of substitutes typically impacts an industry through price competition, there can be other concerns in assessing the threat of substitutes. Consider the substitutability of different types of TV transmission: local station transmission to home TV antennas via the airways versus transmission via cable, satellite, and telephone lines. The new technologies available and the changing structure of the entertainment media are contributing to competition among these substitute means of connecting the home to entertainment. Except in remote areas it is unlikely that cable TV could compete with free TV from an aerial without the greater diversity of entertainment that it affords the customer.
III. Buyer Power
The power of buyers is the impact that customers have on a producing industry. In general, when buyer power is strong, the relationship to the producing industry is near to what an economist terms a monopsony – a market in which there are many suppliers and one buyer. Under such market conditions, the buyer sets the price. In reality few pure monopsonies exist, but frequently there is some asymmetry between a producing industry and buyers. The following tables outline some factors that determine buyer power.
Buyers are Powerful if: |
Example |
Buyers are concentrated – there are a few buyers with significant market share |
DOD purchases from defense contractors |
Buyers purchase a significant proportion of output – distribution of purchases or if the product is standardized |
Circuit City and Sears’ large retail market provides power over appliance manufacturers |
Buyers possess a credible backward integration threat – can threaten to buy producing firm or rival |
Large auto manufacturers’ purchases of tires |
|
|
Buyers are Weak if: |
Example |
Producers threaten forward integration – producer can take over own distribution/retailing |
Movie-producing companies have integrated forward to acquire theaters |
Significant buyer switching costs – products not standardized and buyer cannot easily switch to another product |
IBM’s 360 system strategy in the 1960’s |
Buyers are fragmented (many, different) – no buyer has any particular influence on product or price |
Most consumer products |
Producers supply critical portions of buyers’ input – distribution of purchases |
Intel’s relationship with PC manufacturers |
IV. Supplier PowerA producing industry requires raw materials – labor, components, and other supplies. This requirement leads to buyer-supplier relationships between the industry and the firms that provide it the raw materials used to create products. Suppliers, if powerful, can exert an influence on the producing industry, such as selling raw materials at a high price to capture some of the industry’s profits. The following tables outline some factors that determine supplier power.
Suppliers are Powerful if: |
Example |
Credible forward integration threat by suppliers |
Baxter International, manufacturer of hospital supplies, acquired American Hospital Supply, a distributor |
Suppliers concentrated |
Drug industry’s relationship to hospitals |
Significant cost to switch suppliers |
Microsoft’s relationship with PC manufacturers |
Customers Powerful |
Boycott of grocery stores selling non-union picked grapes |
|
|
Suppliers are Weak if: |
Example |
Many competitive suppliers – product is standardized |
Tire industry relationship to automobile manufacturers |
Purchase commodity products |
Grocery store brand label products |
Credible backward integration threat by purchasers |
Timber producers relationship to paper companies |
Concentrated purchasers |
Garment industry relationship to major department stores |
Customers Weak |
Travel agents’ relationship to airlines |
V. Barriers to Entry / Threat of Entry
It is not only incumbent rivals that pose a threat to firms in an industry; the possibility that new firms may enter the industry also affects competition. In theory, any firm should be able to enter and exit a market, and if free entry and exit exists, then profits always should be nominal. In reality, however, industries possess characteristics that protect the high profit levels of firms in the market and inhibit additional rivals from entering the market. These are barriers to entry.
Barriers to entry are more than the normal equilibrium adjustments that markets typically make. For example, when industry profits increase, we would expect additional firms to enter the market to take advantage of the high profit levels, over time driving down profits for all firms in the industry. When profits decrease, we would expect some firms to exit the market thus restoring a market equilibrium. Falling prices, or the expectation that future prices will fall, deters rivals from entering a market. Firms also may be reluctant to enter markets that are extremely uncertain, especially if entering involves expensive start-up costs. These are normal accommodations to market conditions. But if firms individually (collective action would be illegal collusion) keep prices artificially low as a strategy to prevent potential entrants from entering the market, such entry-deterring pricing establishes a barrier.
Barriers to entry are unique industry characteristics that define the industry. Barriers reduce the rate of entry of new firms, thus maintaining a level of profits for those already in the industry. From a strategic perspective, barriers can be created or exploited to enhance a firm’s competitive advantage. Barriers to entry arise from several sources:
The regulatory authority of the government in restricting competition is historically evident in the banking industry. Until the 1970’s, the markets that banks could enter were limited by state governments. As a result, most banks were local commercial and retail banking facilities. Banks competed through strategies that emphasized simple marketing devices such as awarding toasters to new customers for opening a checking account. When banks were deregulated, banks were permitted to cross state boundaries and expand their markets. Deregulation of banks intensified rivalry and created uncertainty for banks as they attempted to maintain market share. In the late 1970’s, the strategy of banks shifted from simple marketing tactics to mergers and geographic expansion as rivals attempted to expand markets.
The existence of such an economy of scale creates a barrier to entry. The greater the difference between industry MES and entry unit costs, the greater the barrier to entry. So industries with high MES deter entry of small, start-up businesses. To operate at less than MES there must be a consideration that permits the firm to sell at a premium price – such as product differentiation or local monopoly.
Barriers to exit work similarly to barriers to entry. Exit barriers limit the ability of a firm to leave the market and can exacerbate rivalry – unable to leave the industry, a firm must compete. Some of an industry’s entry and exit barriers can be summarized as follows:
Easy to Enter if there is:
|
Difficult to Enter if there is:
|
Easy to Exit if there are:
|
Difficult to Exit if there are:
|
DYNAMIC NATURE OF INDUSTRY RIVALRYOur descriptive and analytic models of industry tend to examine the industry at a given state. The nature and fascination of business is that it is not static. While we are prone to generalize, for example, list GM, Ford, and Chrysler as the “Big 3” and assume their dominance, we also have seen the automobile industry change. Currently, the entertainment and communications industries are in flux. Phone companies, computer firms, and entertainment are merging and forming strategic alliances that re-map the information terrain. Schumpeter and, more recently, Porter have attempted to move the understanding of industry competition from a static economic or industry organization model to an emphasis on the interdependence of forces as dynamic, or punctuated equilibrium, as Porter terms it.
In Schumpeter’s and Porter’s view the dynamism of markets is driven by innovation. We can envision these forces at work as we examine the following changes:
Top 10 US Industrial Firms by Sales 1917 – 1988
|
1917 |
1945 |
1966 |
1983 |
1988 |
1 |
US Steel |
General Motors |
General Motors |
Exxon |
General Motors |
2 |
Swift |
US Steel |
Ford |
General Motors |
Ford |
3 |
Armour |
Standard Oil -NJ |
Standard Oil -NJ (Exxon) |
Mobil |
Exxon |
4 |
American Smelting |
US Steel |
General Electric |
Texaco |
IBM |
5 |
Standard Oil -NJ |
Bethlehem Steel |
Chrysler |
Ford |
General Electric |
6 |
Bethlehem Steel |
Swift |
Mobil |
IBM |
Mobil |
7 |
Ford |
Armour |
Texaco |
Socal (Oil) |
Chrysler |
8 |
DuPont |
Curtiss-Wright |
US Steel |
DuPont |
Texaco |
9 |
American Sugar |
Chrysler |
IBM |
Gulf Oil |
DuPont |
10 |
General Electric |
Ford |
Gulf Oil |
Standard Oil of Indiana |
Philip Morris |
10 Largest US Firms by Assets, 1909 and 1987
|
1909 |
1987 |
1 |
US STEEL |
GM (Not listed in 1909) |
2 |
STANDARD OIL, NJ (Now, EXXON #3) |
SEARS (1909 = 45) |
3 |
AMERICAN TOBACCO (Now, American Brands #52) |
EXXON (Standard Oil trust broken up in 1911) |
4 |
AMERICAN MERCANTILE MARINE (Renamed US Lines; acquired by Kidde, Inc., 1969; sold to McLean Industries, 1978; bankruptcy, 1986 |
IBM (Ranked 68, 1948) |
5 |
INTERNATIONAL HARVESTER (Renamed Navistar #182); divested farm equipment |
FORD (Listed in 1919) |
6 |
ANACONDA COPPER (acquired by ARCO in 1977) |
MOBIL OIL |
7 |
US LEATHER (Liquidated in 1935) |
GENERAL ELECTRIC (1909= 16) |
8 |
ARMOUR (Merged in 1968 with General Host; in 1969 by Greyhound; 1983 sold to ConAgra) |
CHEVRON (Not listed in 1909) |
9 |
AMERICAN SUGAR REFINING (Renamed AMSTAR. In 1967 =320) |
TEXACO (1909= 91) |
10 |
PULLMAN, INC (Acquired by Wheelabrator Frye, 1980; spun-off as Pullman-Peabody, 1981; 1984 sold to Trinity Industries) |
DU PONT (1909= 29) |
GENERIC STRATEGIES TO COUNTER THE FIVE FORCESStrategy can be formulated on three levels:
The business unit level is the primary context of industry rivalry. Michael Porter identified three generic strategies (cost leadership, differentiation, and focus) that can be implemented at the business unit level to create a competitive advantage. The proper generic strategy will position the firm to leverage its strengths and defend against the adverse effects of the five forces.